The world economy is visibly sinking, and the policymakers who are supposed to be its stewards are tying themselves in knots. Or so suggest the results of the G-20 summit held in Shanghai at the end of last month. The International Monetary Fund, having just downgraded its forecast for global growth, warned the assembled G-20 attendees that yet another downgrade was pending. Despite this, all that emerged from the meeting was an anodyne statement about pursuing structural reforms and avoiding beggar-thy-neighbour policies. Once again, monetary policy was left to use the now-familiar phrase as the only game in town. Central banks have kept interest rates low for the better part of eight years. They have experimented with quantitative easing. In their latest contortion, they have moved real interest rates into negative territory. The motivation is sound: someone needs to do something to keep the world economy afloat, and central banks are the only agents capable of acting. The problem is that monetary policy is approaching exhaustion. It is not clear that interest rates can be depressed much further. Negative rates, moreover, have begun to impair the health of the banking system. Charging banks for the privilege of holding reserves raises their cost of doing business. Because households can resort to safe-deposit boxes, its hard for banks to charge depositors for safekeeping their funds. In a weak economy, moreover, banks have little ability to pass on their costs via higher lending rates. In Europe, where experimentation with negative interest rates has gone furthest, bank distress is clearly visible. The solution is straightforward. It is to fix the problem of deficient demand not by attempting to further loosen monetary conditions, but by boosting public spending. Governments should borrow to invest in research, education, and infrastructure. Currently, such investments cost little, given low interest rates. Productive public investment would also enhance the returns on private investment, encouraging firms to undertake additional projects. Thus, it is disturbing to see the refusal of policymakers, particularly in the US and Germany, to even contemplate such action, despite available fiscal space (as record-low treasury-bond yields and virtually every other economic indicator show). In Germany, ideological aversion to budget deficits runs deep. It is rooted in the post-World War II doctrine of ordoliberalism, which counselled that government should enforce contracts and ensure adequate competition but otherwise avoid interfering in the economy. Adherence to this doctrine prevented post war German policymakers from being tempted by excesses like those of Hitler and Stalin. But the cost was high. The ordoliberal emphasis on personal responsibility fostered an unreasoning hostility to the idea that actions that are individually responsible do not automatically produce desirable aggregate outcomes. In other words, it rendered Germans allergic to macroeconomics. The aging of the German population then made it seem urgent to save collectively for retirement by running surpluses. And an exceptional spate of budget deficits following German reunification in 1990 appeared only to aggravate, not solve, reunified Germanys structural problems. Ultimately, hostility to the use of fiscal policy, as with many things German, can be traced to the 1920s, when budget deficits led to hyperinflation. The circumstances today may be entirely different from those in the 1920s, but there is still guilt by association, as every German schoolboy and girl learns at an early age. The US did not experience hyperinflation in the 1920s or at any other time in its history. But for the better part of two centuries, its citizens have been suspicious of federal government power, including the power to run deficits, which is fundamentally a federal prerogative. From independence through the Civil War, that suspicion was strongest in the American South, where it was rooted in the fear that the federal government might abolish slavery. In the mid-twentieth century, during the civil rights movement, it was again the Southern political elite that opposed the muscular use of federal power. Starting in 1964, in conjunction with Democratic President Lyndon Baines Johnsons New Society, the government threatened to withhold federal funding for health, education, and other state and local programs from jurisdictions that resisted legislative and judicial desegregation orders. The result was to render the South a solid Republican bloc and leave its leaders antagonistic to all exercise of federal power except for the enforcement of contracts and competition a hostility that notably included countercyclical macroeconomic policy. Welcome to ordoliberalism, Dixie-style. Wolfgang Schäuble, meet Ted Cruz. Ideological and political prejudices deeply rooted in history will have to be overcome to end the current stagnation. If an extended period of depressed growth following a crisis isnt the right moment to challenge them, then when is?
Top Stories
RELATED ARTICLESMORE FROM AUTHOR
【時事評論】困境未盡 艱難前行
一場新冠疫情,令2020成為人類百年一遇的世紀疫年,8千多萬人感染、逾182萬人死亡; 封城之下,環球經濟大衰退,苦不堪言。儘管疫苗已面世,但距全球有效防疫的目標仍然遙遠。展望2021仍是個艱難年頭,對澳門而言挑戰大過機遇,各位宜有心理準備,保持鬥志,做好防守。
OPINION – Soft figures
The ongoing economic slump has visible implications in casino revenues, visitor flows, and hotel occupation....
【主編前言】諮詢的作用
早前特區政府就南灣湖C區兩份興建司法機關的規劃條件圖作公示,及後在城規會聽取城規會議上交委員討論,並獲大部分委員支持。該兩份規劃圖是關於在現有初院刑事大樓、終審法院及中級法院大樓旁邊,分別興建法院及檢察院、法院設施。近初級法院院的大樓可建最高五十點八米。公示期間兩份規劃圖收到百三份反對意見,主要擔心樓高影響歷史城區,冀降低建築高度。
【總監之言】極具建設性
批判性思維是否值得鼓勵?初步答案似乎明顯“是”,但在《澳門青年政策(2021-2030)》諮詢文件中,這變成了一個相當微不足道的問題。上一個十年(2012-2020年)的藍圖確切地描述了培養具有“批判思維和獨立思考能力”的年輕一代的重要性;然而,在新提出的《政策》版本中,則以“較輕”的態度描述這些特質,因收集所得意見的偏好而捨棄了有關措辭,選擇用“審辨思維”描述“審視和辨識的能力”。根據社會文化司司長的解釋,導致改變用詞的背後原因是之前文件所使用的表述“批判”具有某種貶義或負面含義;她強調,歡迎持批評態度,但應該具有建設性。