I wrote at the beginning of January that economic conditions this year were set to be as weak as in 2015, which was the worst year since the global financial crisis erupted in 2008. And, as has happened repeatedly over the last decade, a few months into the year, others more optimistic forecasts are being revised downward. The underlying problem which has plagued the global economy since the crisis, but has worsened slightly is lack of global aggregate demand. Now, in response, the European Central Bank (ECB) has stepped up its stimulus, joining the Bank of Japan and a couple of other central banks in showing that the zero lower bound the inability of interest rates to become negative is a boundary only in the imagination of conventional economists. And yet, in none of the economies attempting the unorthodox experiment of negative interest rates has there been a return to growth and full employment. In some cases, the outcome has been unexpected: Some lending rates have actually increased. It should have been apparent that most central banks pre-crisis models both the formal models and the mental models that guide policymakers thinking were badly wrong. None predicted the crisis; and in very few of these economies has a semblance of full employment been restored. The ECB famously raised interest rates twice in 2011, just as the euro crisis was worsening and unemployment was increasing to double-digit levels, bringing deflation ever closer. They continued to use the old discredited models, perhaps slightly modified. In these models, the interest rate is the key policy tool, to be dialled up and down to ensure good economic performance. If a positive interest rate doesnt suffice, then a negative interest rate should do the trick. It hasnt. In many economies including Europe and the United States real (inflation-adjusted) interest rates have been negative, sometimes as much as -2%. And yet, as real interest rates have fallen, business investment has stagnated. According to the OECD, the percentage of GDP invested in a category that is mostly plant and equipment has fallen in both Europe and the US in recent years. (In the US, it fell from 8.4% in 2000 to 6.8% in 2014; in the EU, it fell from 7.5% to 5.7% over the same period.) Other data provide a similar picture. Clearly, the idea that large corporations precisely calculate the interest rate at which they are willing to undertake investment and that they would be willing to undertake a large number of projects if only interest rates were lowered by another 25 basis points is absurd. More realistically, large corporations are sitting on hundreds of billions of dollars indeed, trillions if aggregated across the advanced economies because they already have too much capacity. Why build more simply because the interest rate has moved down a little? The small and medium-size enterprises (SMEs) that are willing to borrow couldnt get access to credit before the ECB went negative, and they cant now. Simply put, most firms and especially SMEs cant borrow easily at the T-bill rate. They dont borrow on capital markets. They borrow from banks. And there is a large difference (spread) between the interest rates the banks set and the T-bill rate. Moreover, banks ration. They may refuse to lend to some firms. In other cases, they demand collateral (often real estate). It may come as a shock to non-economists, but banks play no role in the standard economic model that monetary policymakers have used for the last couple of decades. Of course, if there were no banks, there would be no central banks, either; but cognitive dissonance has seldom shaken central bankers confidence in their models. The fact is that the eurozones structure and the ECBs policies have ensured that banks in the underperforming countries, and especially in the crisis countries, are very weak. Deposits have left, and the austerity policies demanded by Germany are prolonging the aggregate-demand shortfall and sustaining high unemployment. In these circumstances, lending is risky, and banks have neither the appetite nor ability to lend, particularly to SMEs (which typically generate the highest number of jobs). A decrease in the real interest rate that on government bonds to -3% or even -4% will make little or no difference. Negative interest rates hurt banks balance sheets, with the wealth effect on banks overwhelming the small increase in incentives to lend. Unless policymakers are careful, lending rates could increase and credit availability decline. There are three further problems. First, low interest rates encourage firms to invest in more capital-intensive technologies, resulting in demand for labour falling in the longer term, even as unemployment declines in the short term. Second, older people who depend on interest income, hurt further, cut their consumption more deeply than those who benefit rich owners of equity increase theirs, undermining aggregate demand today. Third, the perhaps irrational but widely documented search for yield implies that many investors will shift their portfolios toward riskier assets, exposing the economy to greater financial instability. What central banks should be doing is focusing on the flow of credit, which means restoring and maintaining local banks ability and willingness to lend to SMEs. Instead, throughout the world, central banks have focused on the systemically significant banks, the financial institutions whose excessive risk taking and abusive practices caused the 2008 crisis. But a large number of small banks in the aggregate are systemically significant especially if one is concerned about restoring investment, employment, and growth. The big lesson from all of this is captured by the familiar adage, garbage in, garbage out. If central banks continue to use the wrong models, they will continue to do the wrong thing. Of course, even in the best of circumstances, monetary policys ability to restore a slumping economy to full employment may be limited. But relying on the wrong model prevents central bankers from contributing what they can and may even make a bad situation worse.
Top Stories
RELATED ARTICLESMORE FROM AUTHOR
【時事評論】困境未盡 艱難前行
一場新冠疫情,令2020成為人類百年一遇的世紀疫年,8千多萬人感染、逾182萬人死亡; 封城之下,環球經濟大衰退,苦不堪言。儘管疫苗已面世,但距全球有效防疫的目標仍然遙遠。展望2021仍是個艱難年頭,對澳門而言挑戰大過機遇,各位宜有心理準備,保持鬥志,做好防守。
OPINION – Soft figures
The ongoing economic slump has visible implications in casino revenues, visitor flows, and hotel occupation....
【主編前言】諮詢的作用
早前特區政府就南灣湖C區兩份興建司法機關的規劃條件圖作公示,及後在城規會聽取城規會議上交委員討論,並獲大部分委員支持。該兩份規劃圖是關於在現有初院刑事大樓、終審法院及中級法院大樓旁邊,分別興建法院及檢察院、法院設施。近初級法院院的大樓可建最高五十點八米。公示期間兩份規劃圖收到百三份反對意見,主要擔心樓高影響歷史城區,冀降低建築高度。
【總監之言】極具建設性
批判性思維是否值得鼓勵?初步答案似乎明顯“是”,但在《澳門青年政策(2021-2030)》諮詢文件中,這變成了一個相當微不足道的問題。上一個十年(2012-2020年)的藍圖確切地描述了培養具有“批判思維和獨立思考能力”的年輕一代的重要性;然而,在新提出的《政策》版本中,則以“較輕”的態度描述這些特質,因收集所得意見的偏好而捨棄了有關措辭,選擇用“審辨思維”描述“審視和辨識的能力”。根據社會文化司司長的解釋,導致改變用詞的背後原因是之前文件所使用的表述“批判”具有某種貶義或負面含義;她強調,歡迎持批評態度,但應該具有建設性。